000 | 01984nam a22002657a 4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
003 | ZW-GwMSU | ||
005 | 20240318080331.0 | ||
008 | 240313b |||||||| |||| 00| 0 eng d | ||
040 |
_aMSU _bEnglish _cMSU _erda |
||
050 | 0 | 0 | _aHB73 JOU |
100 | 1 |
_aPhilipson, Tomas J. _eauthor |
|
245 | 1 | 0 |
_aAntitrust in the not‐for‐profit sector/ _ccreated by Tomas J. Philipson and Richard A. Posner |
264 |
_aChicago : _bUniversity of Chicago Press, _c2009. |
||
336 |
_2rdacontent _atext _btxt |
||
337 |
_2rdamedia _aunmediated _bn |
||
338 |
_2rdacarrier _avolume _bnc |
||
440 |
_aJournal of Law and Economics _vVolume 52, number 1 |
||
520 | _aAlthough the not‐for‐profit sector contributes greatly to aggregate output in many industries, there has been little explicit analysis of the economic consequences of applying antitrust policy in this sector. Despite the differences between for‐profit and nonprofit firms stressed in conventional economic analyses, U.S. antitrust law generally does not distinguish between these two organizational forms. This paper argues that, under plausible assumptions and with possible exceptions, the same incentives to restrain trade exist in the nonprofit sector as in the for‐profit sector. Altruistic firms benefit from exploiting market power, even when they would price below cost in the absence of competition. In fact, the efficiency gains from antitrust policy may often be larger for nonprofit firms. Therefore, a policy of promoting competition has social value even when producers’ motivations are altruistic. The argument for uniform antitrust treatment of the two sectors extends to exemptions from antitrust law as well | ||
650 |
_aAltruism _vAntitrust _xCost efficiency |
||
650 |
_aEconomic competition _vIndustrial market _xIndustrial output |
||
650 |
_aMarginal costs _vMarket power _xMarket prices |
||
700 | 1 |
_aPosner, Richard A. _eco author |
|
856 | _uhttps://doi.org/10.1086/589704 | ||
942 |
_2lcc _cJA |
||
999 |
_c164317 _d164317 |