000 | 01768nam a22002657a 4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
003 | ZW-GwMSU | ||
005 | 20240318085338.0 | ||
008 | 240313b |||||||| |||| 00| 0 eng d | ||
022 | _a00222186 | ||
040 |
_aMSU _bEnglish _cMSU _erda |
||
050 | 0 | 0 | _aHB73 JOU |
100 | 1 |
_aAkee, Randall _eauthor |
|
245 | 1 | 0 |
_aCheckerboards and coase : _bthe effect of property institutions on efficiency in housing markets/ _ccreated by Randall Akee |
264 | 1 |
_aChicago : _bUniversity of Chicago Press, _c2009. |
|
336 |
_2rdacontent _atext _btxt |
||
337 |
_2rdamedia _aunmediated _bn |
||
338 |
_2rdacarrier _avolume _bnc |
||
440 |
_aJournal of Law and Economics _vVolume 52, number 2 |
||
520 | _aIn the late 1800s, Palm Springs, California, was evenly divided into 1‐mile‐square blocks—like a checkerboard—and property rights were assigned in alternating blocks to the Agua Caliente tribe and a non‐Indian landowner by the U.S. federal government. The quasi‐experimental nature of land assignment holds land quality constant across the two types of landowners. Sales, mortgaging, and leasing restrictions on the Agua Caliente Reservation land created large transaction costs to development on those lands; consequently, there was very little housing investment. The non‐Indian blocks, which were extensively developed, provide a benchmark for efficient outcomes for the Agua Caliente lands. Once the restrictions on Agua Caliente lands were relaxed in 1959, the number of homes and real estate values converged to t | ||
650 |
_aHousing _vLand tenure _xLand trusts |
||
650 |
_aLand use change _vLeases _xNative Americans |
||
650 |
_aProperty trusts _vReal estate investment trusts _xReal estate taxes |
||
856 | _ug/10.1086/592718 | ||
942 |
_2lcc _cJA |
||
999 |
_c164315 _d164315 |