000 01768nam a22002657a 4500
003 ZW-GwMSU
005 20240318085338.0
008 240313b |||||||| |||| 00| 0 eng d
022 _a00222186
040 _aMSU
_bEnglish
_cMSU
_erda
050 0 0 _aHB73 JOU
100 1 _aAkee, Randall
_eauthor
245 1 0 _aCheckerboards and coase :
_bthe effect of property institutions on efficiency in housing markets/
_ccreated by Randall Akee
264 1 _aChicago :
_bUniversity of Chicago Press,
_c2009.
336 _2rdacontent
_atext
_btxt
337 _2rdamedia
_aunmediated
_bn
338 _2rdacarrier
_avolume
_bnc
440 _aJournal of Law and Economics
_vVolume 52, number 2
520 _aIn the late 1800s, Palm Springs, California, was evenly divided into 1‐mile‐square blocks—like a checkerboard—and property rights were assigned in alternating blocks to the Agua Caliente tribe and a non‐Indian landowner by the U.S. federal government. The quasi‐experimental nature of land assignment holds land quality constant across the two types of landowners. Sales, mortgaging, and leasing restrictions on the Agua Caliente Reservation land created large transaction costs to development on those lands; consequently, there was very little housing investment. The non‐Indian blocks, which were extensively developed, provide a benchmark for efficient outcomes for the Agua Caliente lands. Once the restrictions on Agua Caliente lands were relaxed in 1959, the number of homes and real estate values converged to t
650 _aHousing
_vLand tenure
_xLand trusts
650 _aLand use change
_vLeases
_xNative Americans
650 _aProperty trusts
_vReal estate investment trusts
_xReal estate taxes
856 _ug/10.1086/592718
942 _2lcc
_cJA
999 _c164315
_d164315