000 | 01602nam a22002417a 4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
003 | ZW-GwMSU | ||
005 | 20230919094111.0 | ||
008 | 230919b |||||||| |||| 00| 0 eng d | ||
040 |
_aMSU _cMSU _erda |
||
100 | _aSTODDER, James | ||
245 | _aThe strange persistence of consumer surplus | ||
264 |
_aNew York _bTaylor & Francis _c2013 |
||
336 |
_2rdacontent _atext _btxt |
||
337 |
_2rdamedia _aunmediated _bn |
||
338 |
_2rdacarrier _avolume _bnc |
||
440 |
_aApplied Economics Letters _vVolume , number , |
||
520 | _aDespite its abandonment in theoretical work, a literature search shows that variation in consumer surplus (VCS) is the overwhelming choice in applied work – not compensating variation (CV) or equivalent variation (EV). How can this be explained? Besides the obvious ease of computation, there are three good reasons for the persistence of VCS. (1) The Willig bounds on VCS usually give close upper and lower bounds on CV and EV, respectively, and are thus conservative in the estimation of EV. (2) Without integrability, all three measures are inaccurate. Common quasi-linear utility assumptions for VCS, however, imply integrability. (3) Even with integrability, the expected values of highly nonlinear CV and EV measures cannot be determined by substituting prices or quantities into the estimated equations; simulations are required. Thus, VCS is not only simpler, it may also be more accurate. | ||
650 | _awilling bounds | ||
650 | _aintegrability | ||
650 | _anon - linearity | ||
856 | _uhttps://doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2013.788776 | ||
942 |
_2lcc _cJA |
||
999 |
_c163306 _d163306 |